Black-Scholes model of option pricing

Consider a public company with stock price at time
. A European style option on the stock of this company is a contract to have the option to buy the stock at a predetermined price on a predetermined future time. The option is described by the strike price
, the strike time
and its price
. Paying
to buy an option gives us the opportunity to buy the stock for the strike price
at the strike time
. At time
, the worth of the option depends on the value of the stock
. If the stock has fallen below the strike price
, i.e., if
the option becomes worthless because it is more convenient to pay the actual price
for the stock and forgo the option. If, on the contrary, the price has risen beyond
, i.e., if
we can realize a gain
by exercising the option to buy the stock at price
. This gain can be cashed immediately by reselling the stock at the current price
. We can thus write the worth
of the option as
where denotes projection on the positive numbers.
The gain to be realized by the trading strategy “buy option at time , exercise the option at time
if
, sell stock at price
” depends on the difference between
and
. It is not exactly the difference because it is not equivalent to own
at time
and
at time
. In particular, while the proposed investment strategy incurs some risk of loosing the initial investment
, it is possible to invest
in a risk-free money market account. If the interest in the money market account is
continuously compounded, the worth of the money market investment at time
is
. Consequently, when comparing investment and payoff it is fairer to compare
with
because growing
to
is literally effortless. Equivalently, we can compare
to
because capital
at time
can be grown to
at time
through a risk-free money market investment. The latter comparison is the one commonly used and, in general, we say that a capital
at time
has a present value or a time-zero value of
. We may also refer to
as the discounted worth. Using the option’s worth expression, we can compute the discounted gain of an option investment as
The relevant question here is what is a fair price for an option with strike price
to be exercised at time
. The answer to this question is given by the Black-Scholes formula for option pricing that uses expectations on the future behavior of the stock to determine the option’s price
. To understand Black-Scholes formula, we need to introduce the Geometric Brownian motion model of stock prices, discuss the concept of arbitrages, and define risk neutral measures. The geometric Brownian motion model of stock prices is presented next. For arbitrages and the risk neutral measure you’ll have to wait for the class.
Geometric Brownian motion model of stock prices
It suffices to examine a graph with the evolution of a stock price, e.g., Fig. 1, to realize that stock prices are, to some extent, random. To construct a stochastic model of stock prices, notice that variations in a stock price are likely to be proportional to the price of the stock . That is, if the price of the stock is
, a variation of plus or minus
is akin to a variation of plus or minus
, when the price is
. A particular class of stochastic processes with such property is geometric Brownian motion (GBM). This model presupposes that relative variations on the price
can be described as a Brownian motion with drift. Specifically, it assumes that changes in prices are according to the expression
where is normally distributed with mean
and variance
independently of
. Definition of a GBM also requires relative price changes
and
in disjoint time intervals to be independent. In the context of stock pricing, the mean
represents the stock’s drift and the variance
its volatility.
An equivalent characterization of a GBM is to state that a process is a GBM if its logarithm
is a regular Brownian motion (BM) with drift. Indeed, taking logarithms in both sides of the previous equation yields
The two conditions imposed on , namely that
is normal with mean
and variance
and that
and
are independent for disjoint time intervals, along with the relationship just derived imply by definition that
is a BM.
An important observation to make here is to consider a discretization in time steps of fixed duration , say
, and to define the discrete time stochastic process
as
It follows from the GBM model, that variables are independent identically distributed normals with mean
and variance
. This is an important observation because it allows us to infer the parameters
and
from empirical data. Indeed, let it be available a historic sequence of stock prices
for
, taken from a realization
of the GBM stochastic process
. From
we compute
to obtain a realization of the stochastic process
. The drift parameter
can then be estimated by the sample mean
and the volatility parameter can be estimated by the sample variance
While we have given a justification for why GBM is a plausible model for stock prices, the actual motivation for their use, is that GBM models have been observed to provide reasonable fits of empirical stock price sequences. This fit is easy to observe using drift and volatility estimates and
computed from empirical data. If a GBM with drift
and volatility
is a good model for the evolution of a stock price, then the variables
have a probability density function (pdf)
. We can then estimate the pdf of
using a histogram of the
and compare it with the pdf
.
As a particular example, consider the stock price of Cisco during the year 2009 depicted in Fig. 1. More recent data for this stock and others is publicly available, see, e.g. Google finance. The comparison between the normal pdf and the histogram of
is shown in Fig. 2. A comparison between the cumulative distribution function (cdf) and the empirical cdf is also shown. From either picture a reasonable fit between model and observations is seen.


Figure 2. Fit of Cisco’s stock price (CSCO) to geometric Brownian motion (GBM) model. If GBM is a good model of stock price variations, the relative changes in stock prices from closing date to closing date are independent identically distributed normal random variables. Empirical probability distribution function (left) and cumulative distribution function (right) of CSCO relative changes in closing price are compared with a normal random variable. From either picture a reasonable fit between model and observations is seen.